CEIF Micro Thesis - Alleviating Wage Dependence
Document Description
The following document, “Alleviating Wage Dependence,” is a pragmatic blueprint for transitioning households from wage-based to property-based earnings in the age of automation.
Table of Contents
List of Figures
Figure 1. Shrinking Wage Share vs. Rising Real GDP (2000-2024)
Figure 2. American Household Income Mix (2000-2024)
Figure 3. Where the ‘Missing’ Wage Share Went (2000 vs. 2024)
Figure 4. Estimated Distribution of American Property Income by Economic Class (2022)
Figure 5. Who Receives Federal Transfer Dollars? (Illustrative Shares)
Figure 6. Classic Phillips Curve vs. Inverted Curve under Agentic OS
List of Acronyms
ABI Agent-Based Income
CSF Community-Sourced Fund
SSI Self-Sovereign Identity
TPI Tokenized Product Investment
1. Executive Summary
As automation accelerates and labor’s share of national income continues to decline, income from traditional employment alone is no longer sufficient to support broad-based prosperity. Productivity gains—once distributed through wages—are increasingly captured as capital income, concentrating wealth among asset holders and leaving most households with shrinking economic agency.
This white paper presents a pragmatic and investable blueprint for transitioning household income from wage dependency to data-driven property returns. By converting everyday behavioral engagement into economic inputs scored, secured, and rewarded through algorithmic rights and smart-contract enforcement, Agentic OS establishes a new income architecture for the automation era.
At its core is Agent-Based Income (ABI): a programmable, compounding stream of capital income funded by retail margins and distributed through Tokenized Product Investments (TPIs). ABI transforms user behavior into ownership, enabling households to build wealth through participation rather than employment.
This system provides a structural response to underemployment, a scalable alternative to fragile government transfers, and a macroeconomic stabilizer for economies facing rising technological deflation. ABI does not merely patch the gap left by fading wages—it redefines the foundations of earning, spending, and prosperity in a world where behavior becomes the new labor.
2. The Great Decoupling — Where the Surplus Goes
Technological progress has become capital-biased: it raises the return on machines and software faster than it lifts wages. (Economists Baumol and Bostrom coined the frame.) In the United States, labor’s share of national income slipped from roughly 54% in 2000 to 48% in 2024, even though GDP kept rising. The extra wealth is real; it simply bypasses paychecks.

3. Labor Substitution, the Agency Paradox, and Keynesian Demand
But understanding where the surplus goes is only half the puzzle. The deeper transformation lies in how automation not only redirects income, but redefines work itself. As tasks migrate from humans to machines, we enter a feedback loop where productivity soars, yet consumer power collapses. Welcome to the age of labor substitution and the agency paradox.
Labor substitution is the heart of post-labor economics: whenever a machine can deliver the same task faster, safer, or cheaper than a person, the task migrates from labor to capital. The pattern is centuries-old (think steam looms), but today’s AI, robotics, and cloud software compress the cycle from decades to months. A 2023 McKinsey update, for instance, estimates that generative AI alone could automate work activities representing 30% of U.S. hours by 2030.¹ That scale of substitution pulls two economic levers at once:
Cost lever (firm level). Replacing workers with software slashes operating costs, boosts margins, and, in a perfectly competitive world, forces rivals to do the same or lose price competitiveness.
Income lever (macro level). The displaced wages don’t vanish; they reappear mainly as higher profits, dividends, and stock-based compensation—income channels owned disproportionately by the top decile.
When firms everywhere pull the cost lever, we meet the economic agency paradox: production capacity and profits soar, yet the very consumers who once drew paychecks from those firms can’t afford the new output.
Keynes anticipated this feedback loop. In The General Theory, he argued that aggregate demand is the brake-pedal on growth; if household income doesn’t rise alongside productivity, inventories pile up, investment stalls, and the economy underperforms its potential. Put differently, a robot that boosts efficiency by 30% is only a blessing if someone, somewhere, has 30% more spending power. Without a mechanism to “recycle” productivity gains into household balance sheets, the system risks chronic demand shortfall.
The agency paradox and Keynesian demand gap are two sides of one coin:
Labor substitution reallocates income up the distribution (wages → profits).
Keynesian dynamics punish economies where the median household can’t translate those gains back into spending.
4. Why Wages and Government Transfers Can’t Plug the Hole
If productivity gains flow upward—toward capital, not workers—then we must ask: can our traditional income scaffolding still support broad prosperity? Unfortunately, the answer is no. Wages and government transfers, the twin pillars of 20th-century household income, are now structurally ill-equipped to plug the growing gap.
Today about 60% of U.S. household income is wages, 20% property returns, 20% government transfers.

There’s been a structural re-routing of income flows as technology and global competition erode labor’s bargaining power. When firms automate, the savings they once paid out in broad wages are captured first as higher operating margins. A portion of those margins is distributed to shareholders as dividends (and thus shows up as “property income”), but a far larger slice is retained on corporate balance sheets—financing stock buy-backs, acquisitions, and share-based executive pay. Because the top 10 percent of U.S. households own roughly 90 percent of equities, the windfall accrues disproportionately to wealthy asset holders and senior managers whose compensation is equity-linked. Meanwhile, middle- and lower-income workers—who hold little stock and rely mainly on wages—see their share of national income shrink. In short, the same productivity surplus that once spread across millions of paychecks is now concentrated in corporate profits and capital gains, funneling purchasing power upward rather than recycling it through the broader consumer base.
Figure 3 makes one point unmistakable: the six-to-nine-percentage-point drop in the wage share of U.S. national income since 2000 has not vanished from the economy—it has moved. Only a thin slice of that “missing” labor income appears in the orange band, representing dividends, interest, and rents that are actually paid out to households each year. The bulk of the shift shows up in the red band: retained corporate profits, stock buy-backs, and unrealized capital gains that inflate asset values but are not recorded as annual household income. In effect, dollars once spread across millions of paychecks are now parked on corporate balance sheets or accrue to the wealthiest asset holders, bypassing the spending power of most households. Government transfers (pink) remain largely flat, so they do little to offset the demand gap created by shrinking wages and concentrated capital gains.

The stacked bars show how a nine-point decline in wage share between 2000 and 2024 reappears mainly as retained profits and unrealized gains (red band). Only a small slice shows up as distributed property income (orange). Government transfers remain flat for illustration. This makes it clear that the “missing” wages don’t disappear—they migrate into corporate earnings and asset-price growth that don’t hit most household balance sheets.
Over the past three decades, income and wealth have progressively concentrated among existing asset holders. As labor’s share of national income shrank, the flow that once arrived as wages increasingly re-emerged as dividends, capital gains, and corporate cash—channels dominated by the wealthiest households.

5. Government Transfers — A Vital Cushion, but No Cure
Government transfers—Social Security, Medicare, Medicaid, SNAP, unemployment insurance, and the pandemic cheques—have climbed from about 12% of personal income in 2000 to roughly 18% in 2024. At first glance that looks like a strong counter-weight to falling wages, yet the way those dollars are distributed (and financed) reveals why transfers cannot fully solve the post-labor income gap.

Middle-quintile dominance. Because Social Security and Medicare are quasi-universal above 65, roughly 60% of transfer dollars flow to the middle 60% of households. The poorest quintile relies on transfers for most of its cash income, yet it never receives more than about one-third of the national transfer pool.
Top-quintile slice. High-income retirees still collect large Social-Security cheques and universal Medicare coverage, so the wealthiest fifth consistently claims 15–20% of all transfer dollars.
Shock spikes. Crisis years—2009 and especially 2020—send the transfer line sharply up, but those jumps recede when emergency programs expire.
5.1. Four Structural Limits
Revenue erosion. Transfers are funded mainly by payroll and income taxes. As automation pushes the wage share down, the payroll-tax base shrinks just when outlays rise. Capital income that replaces wages is taxed more lightly and unrealized gains are untaxed, widening the fiscal gap.
Political volatility. Congress has changed Social-Security payroll taxes sixteen times since 1977. Pandemic relief worth ~4 ppts of GDP disappeared within 24 months.
Debt can paper over crises, not structural gaps. Re-running a Covid-scale borrowing binge every decade to offset the $1.7 T annual wage loss would push federal debt well beyond sustainable ratios.
Consumption dollars, not investment dollars. Transfers arrive as money to spend, not as assets that compound. They stabilize demand but leave long-run wealth concentration untouched.
Take-away. Transfers remain essential for basic security, yet they cannot permanently replace disappearing wages. Their tax base is fading, their flows are politically fragile, and they build no new household capital. That is why the post-labor solution must add an automatic, universally held capital rail—data dividends feeding user-owned assets that generate spendable Agent-Based Income (ABI)—so every household share in the productivity surplus that automation creates.
5.2. Summary
Income source
Share of household income
Structural weakness
Wages
≈ 60% of U.S. household income (BEA, 2024)
Shrinking as automation accelerates. From 2000 to 2024, the national wage share fell ~6 percentage points even while GDP grew ~50%.
Transfers
≈ 20% (Social Security, Medicare, SNAP, unemployment, etc.)
Politically volatile:
• SNAP benefits expanded 29% during the pandemic and then dropped 15% in 2023 when emergency allotments expired.
• Congress adjusted Social-Security payroll taxes 16 times since 1977 and faces a projected trust-fund shortfall by 2035.
Property returns
≈ 20%
Access is highly skewed:
• Top 10% of U.S. households now own 89% of all corporate equity and mutual-fund shares (Federal Reserve, SCF 2022).
• Fewer than 28 % of households hold any individual stocks; median direct holding is $15,000, well below the accredited-investor threshold of $1 million.
• Only 14% of Black and 17% of Hispanic households own equities directly, vs. 35% of White households.
5.3. Why the Gap Matters
Transfers are political. Benefits expand or contract with each administration, making them an unreliable replacement for disappearing wages.
Conventional property is gated. Brokerage minimums, accreditation rules, and financial literacy hurdles leave the bottom 90% with little exposure to the very capital gains that automation inflates.
A resilient economy must shift everyday earnings toward universally accessible property income, while leaving public transfers as a floor, not a primary income pillar.
6. Inverting the Phillips Curve — A Surplus-Recycling Strategy
Sections 1–3 diagnosed a structural imbalance: wages are no longer keeping pace with productivity, traditional transfers are too politically and fiscally brittle to compensate, and demand is at risk of decoupling from output. If rising efficiency lowers production costs without lifting household income, the result is chronic underconsumption, even in prosperous economies.
Before designing a solution, we must clarify what success looks like at the macro level.
Historically, that benchmark has been shaped by the Phillips Curve, a model linking employment levels to inflation. But the assumptions that underpin it are unraveling. In a tech-dominant economy, we need a new curve—one that treats falling production costs not as a deflationary risk, but as an income opportunity.
6.1. Why the Phillips Curve is Fraying
Since its debut in 1958, the Phillips Curve has guided how policymakers think about growth, inflation, and employment. Its basic shape is intuitive: as unemployment falls, wages rise, and so do prices. Inflation becomes the cost of full employment, and central banks manage this trade-off using tools like interest rates, quantitative easing, and forward guidance.
But today’s economic dynamics stretch that logic. Automation and globalization exert persistent downward pressure on production costs, even in tight labor markets. Meanwhile, most household demand remains wage-dependent. The result? A flatter curve: prices stay tame, but any progress on cost efficiency is not translating into broadly distributed income.
When job losses do occur, the system has no built-in offset. Wages fall. Spending power shrinks. Demand slips, despite high productivity and strong balance sheets at the top.
6.2. What a Post-Wage Economy Needs
To break this cycle, any durable framework must flip the trade-off. That means building an income engine that:
Design Principle
System Goal
Captures productivity surplus
Every marginal cost reduction—especially those from automation—must generate distributable surplus.
Recycles it automatically
Surplus should flow to households without relying on wages, taxation, or fiscal transfers.
Scales with deflation
The more production costs fall, the more income households receive, turning efficiency into demand.
In this model, falling production costs are not a threat to demand but a new source of it. The income rail must invert the original Phillips logic: instead of job growth causing inflation, cost savings cause income growth—without inflation.
Baumol-Bostrom shows why wages fade; Keynes shows why demand will crater unless surplus reaches households. The surplus-recycling strategy routes that surplus: data dividends finance TPIs; TPIs generate ABI; Community-Sourced Funds (CSFs) and Money-Ties broaden ownership; algorithmic rights lock in fairness. Automation still does the work, but people keep earning through property, not payroll.
This surplus-recycling strategy offers a transitional mechanism to reduce society’s dependence on wages as automation increases marginal efficiencies and displaces both employment and underemployment. As machines take over more productive functions, economies must evolve a new income architecture—one that decouples purchasing power from traditional jobs. By converting behavioral data into dividend-generating digital property, Agent-Based Income (ABI) forms a bridge: from earned wages to owned capital, from labor dependence to platform-distributed wealth. This isn’t a temporary workaround—it’s a structural foundation for prosperity in a world transitioning from labor to one driven by the semantics of user behavior.
This system doesn't just restore individual earning power; it reshapes the macroeconomic feedback loop that links income, prices, and demand. In traditional models, productivity gains that lower production costs tend to weaken household income. The surplus-recycling strategy reverses that logic. By routing productivity-driven retail margins into ABI, the same forces that once suppressed demand now expand it. To understand how this flips the economy’s supply-demand calculus, we turn to one of macroeconomics’ most enduring frameworks: the Phillips Curve.
6.3. What the Classic Phillips Curve Is (and Why Central Banks Still Care)
Origin. In 1958, A. W. Phillips plotted a convex, downward-sloping relationship between wage inflation and unemployment in UK data. Later refinements substituted price inflation, but the shape endured: lower joblessness led to higher inflation.
Modern policy use. Every major central bank still maintains an operational version of the curve. Adjusting interest rates, tapering QE, or managing wage expectations are all tools for navigating it:
Monetary Tool
Intended Move on the Curve
Rate hike
↑ unemployment → ↓ inflation
QE / rate cut
↓ unemployment → ↑ inflation
Forward guidance
Anchor wage expectations to prevent shifts
Because most spending power is still wage-driven, policymakers must constantly balance jobs and prices.
6.4. Why the Curve Frays in a Tech-Dominant Economy
Automation and global supply chains now hold prices down, even at full employment. But when layoffs do occur, demand collapses, because wages remain the primary household lifeline. The result is a flatter but still binding trade-off: inflation is muted, but any disinflationary success still shows up as job loss and income fragility.
6.5. “Inverting the Curve” in Surplus-Recycling Terms
Definition: redesign the relationship so that forces that normally weaken demand (e.g., cost-cutting through tech) instead boost household purchasing power.
How this works:
Full retail margin → data-dividend principal As technological productivity reduces costs, retail margins (as a percentage of price) increases. Since 100% of that margin is tokenized and credited to shoppers, every cost decline enlarges the income pool.
TPIs recycle surplus → ABI Inventory resells at markup; 70% of the net profit flows back to users as passive income (ABI) within weeks, not quarters. More margin, more TPIs, more ABI.
Algorithmic rights enforce payout Ownership, auditability, and auto-dividends are baked into the code, avoiding wage spiral dynamics and ensuring surplus is captured equitably.
Result: As technology cuts costs, real household income rises, keeping demand buoyant without requiring wage growth.
6.6. Side-by-Side Picture
Classic Phillips Curve
Inverted Curve via Surplus Recycling
X-axis: Unemployment rate
X-axis: % of households with meaningful ABI
Y-axis: Inflation rate (+)
Y-axis: Price-level change (− = deflation)
Slope: Downward convex
Slope: Downward convex (mirrored)
Dynamic: ↓ unemployment → ↑ inflation
↑ ABI coverage → ↓ prices
Policy logic: Trade jobs for price stability
Policy outcome: Cheaper goods → income growth → steady demand
(Note: the right-hand X-axis can be interpreted as a proxy for the share of households accessing surplus via passive income mechanisms.)
6.7. Why This Matters for the Income-Shift
The flywheel introduced in Section 5—data dividend → CSF → TPI → ABI—has a systemic payoff: it relieves the pressure on wages as the sole vehicle for sustaining demand. Once households receive a baseline income through property-linked channels, deflation is no longer a demand killer—it's a demand amplifier. The same surplus that once accumulated on corporate ledgers now flows back through consumer wallets, closing the loop between productivity and prosperity.

Here are the two convex curves with clear arrows and labels:
Left panel – Classic Phillips Curve Moving A → B lowers unemployment but raises inflation, illustrating the central-bank trade-off.
Right panel – Inverted Curve (Agentic OS) Moving A → B increases the share of households earning ABI while prices drift from mild inflation toward deflation—a mirror image of the traditional curve.
6.8. How Central Banks Manage the Classic Curve
Tool
Target
Why it matters on Panel A
Policy-rate hikes/cuts
Aggregate demand
Slide economy up or down the jobs-vs-inflation curve.
QE / QT
Long-bond yields
Add or drain demand when rates hit zero.
Forward guidance
Wage-price expectations
Keep the curve from “unanchoring.”
Because demand is wage-driven, tightening policy cools both prices and pay-cheques.
6.9. How the Agentic OS Fly-Wheel Flips the Curve
Fly-wheel step (see Section 5)
Shift on Panel B
100 % retail margin → data-dividend principal
Bigger tech savings = bigger principal ⇒ ABI coverage (X) moves right.
TPIs recycle surplus → ABI
Profits return fast, lifting spending power even as prices slide; ABI growth pulls Y-axis down toward deflation.
Algorithmic-rights layer
Hard-codes payouts & data ownership, anchoring expectations without wage bargaining.
Demand no longer relies on rising wages. As technology reduces prices, the margin pool increases, which in turn raises ABI, so lower prices raise real household income instead of squeezing it.
6.10. Visual Comparison
Panel A is convex downward: dropping joblessness from 4% to 6% cuts inflation sharply, but further moves yield diminishing gains.
Panel B mirrors that shape: the first 10 pp rise in ABI coverage brings mild deflation, but once a majority of households receive ABI the curve steepens—bigger margin pools push prices down faster while demand stays buoyant.
6.11. Take-Away
Agentic OS doesn’t flatten the Phillips Curve; it flips it. By routing every retail-margin dollar into household capital, it turns technology-driven price declines from a macro headache into a purchasing-power amplifier, completing the shift of household income from wages to broad-based property returns.
7. Algorithmic Rights & Data Sovereignty — The New bargaining Power
With neither wages nor welfare able to reclaim the surplus, the question shifts from "How do we get paid?" to "Where does our leverage come from in a post-labor world?" In the past, collective bargaining and labor laws did the job. In a software-first economy, that power must move to where value is created now: inside data flows and algorithms. “Algorithmic rights” are the legal-technical layer that forces productive surplus into household wallets.
7.1. Why Labor Rights Stop Where Automation Starts
Old lever
What it protected
Why it weakens under automation
Right to organize & strike
Withhold labor → halt production
A robot arm never joins a picket line.
Minimum wage
Floors hourly pay
Hours vanish when tasks go to code.
Occupational safety & anti-discrimination
Protect humans at work
Fewer humans = smaller coverage base.
Once software does the work, the negotiation must shift to data flows and algorithm logic—the true inputs of a digital firm.
7.2. The Four Pillars of Algorithmic Rights
Pillar
Plain-English promise
Technical anchor
1. Data sovereignty
“My data, my terms.” You can refuse, license, or revoke its use.
Self-Sovereign Identity (SSI) + encrypted data vaults.
2. Participatory algorithmic governance
“I help write the rules my agent runs.” One-click votes or auto-delegation.
On-chain proposals; liquid-democracy smart contracts.
3. Auditability
“Anyone can read the code.” Black-box algorithms are outlawed for core functions.
Open-source repo hashes anchored to the same chain that pays dividends.
4. Algorithmic dividends & liability
“If my data creates surplus, I get paid; if it causes harm, I get restitution.”
Escrowed margin pool (data-fund); programmable insurance pools fed by protocol fees.
Put together, these four pillars replace the wage bargain: every time your data trains a model or your click boosts conversion, the resulting cash must flow back automatically.
7.3. How the Payout Actually Works (Micro-Flow)
Purchase event Retail margin → data fund escrow.
Engagement scoring Your “data signal” (search, review, share) is hashed → compared network-wide in real time.
Dividend split Escrow releases Tripto tokens pro-rata into your wallet.
On-chain receipt Hash of the payout & model weights are posted to a public Merkle tree — auditability enforced.
Opt-out / revoke If you disable a data category, future escrows exclude it; the model retrains or pays a higher license fee.
7.4. Enforcement — Why This Can’t Be Hand-Waved Away
Code as contract. Dividends and liability triggers live in immutable smart-contracts; no “trust us” middleman.
Regulatory dovetail. The wallet UID also stores consent receipts that satisfy GDPR / CCPA.
Economic penalty. A DAO-controlled slashing pool fines any service that feeds un-hashed or black-box models into the network.
8. The Agentic OS Wealth Engine — From Labor Paychecks to Behavior-Powered Ownership
Rights, however, only matter if they result in real income. With algorithmic guarantees in place, the next challenge is operational: how do we turn engagement—searching, shopping, sharing—into capital? That’s where the Agentic OS wealth engine comes in: a compounding loop that transforms data into dividends, and behavior into ownership.
Below is a plain-language walkthrough of what happens each time an item is bought in the Agentic marketplace. The process converts a retail margin into principal (your data dividend), funnels that principal into fractional assets (TPIs), and then pays out yield (ABI). The loop restarts automatically, so every purchase grows the user’s capital base without extra clicks, taxes, or budget fights.
Step
Cash-flow source
What the system does
Why it matters
1. Data Dividend (Principal)
100 % of the retail margin on your purchase
Goes into a network-wide data-fund escrow. In real time the protocol scores each buyer’s data engagement (searches, reviews, shares, dwell time) relative to everyone else and credits that percentage of the fund to the buyer in Tripto tokens.
Every act of shopping turns into investable principal; no one is left out because they “only” spent $10.
2. Community-Sourced Funds (CSFs)
Tripto principal from thousands of buyers
Pools the tokens and bulk-buys inventory at wholesale, then mints Tokenized Product Investments (TPIs) that represent fractional ownership of that inventory batch.
Pooling shaves procurement costs and lets $5 clips buy a slice of assets that once required $5,000.
3. TPI Allocation (User-Investment-Profile Fit)
Newly minted TPIs
The platform’s recommender matches each fractional lot to users whose risk / sector / liquidity profile needs it. Portfolios diversify automatically.
Users don’t have to hand-pick stocks; the system builds a balanced “e-commerce portfolio” tuned to their preferences and goals.
4. TPIs ⇒ Agent-Based Income (ABI)
Net profit when the inventory sells (e.g., 25% markup)
After fees and reserves, 70% of that profit flows back to the TPI holders as ABI. Users can (a) withdraw it, (b) let the re-investment protocol roll it into the next TPI mint, or (c) top it up with outside cash for faster compounding.
ABI is capital income that scales with the marketplace, not with payrolls or legislative cycles.
5. Reinvestment Loop
Data dividends + ABI + optional top-ups
Each month the new principal (data dividend + any reinvested ABI) joins the next CSF round, compounding the user’s stake.
Purchases, engagement, and yield feed one another, converting behavior into a growing asset base.
Money-Ties note – Money-Ties are social squads inside the app that earn bonus engagement points when members shop or review together. Those points boost each member’s data-engagement score in Step 1, increasing the slice of the data fund they capture—yet the ownership of TPIs remains strictly fractional and individual.
Quick scale check (illustrative pilot)
User spend: $300 / month ⇒ $45 margin (15 %) → $45 Tripto principal
Marketplace turnover: 1.5 × / month at 25 % markup
User share of profit: 70 % ⇒ $11.8 ABI in month 1
Principal for month 2 = $45 + $11.8 = $56.8, and so on.
Under these parameters a single user’s cumulative ABI rises from $12 in month 1 to ≈ $2,300 by month 12, because every month’s yield piggybacks on the next month’s principal. Swap in faster turnover or higher margins and the slope steepens; lower them and it flattens.
(The companion chart can plot those scenarios side-by-side for investors who want to see sensitivity ranges.)
Bottom line: Agentic OS replaces “labor → wage” with “behavior → data dividend → TPI → ABI.” Every retail margin dollar is recycled into household capital, every sale drips yield back to the buyer, and every loop compounds the next, turning ordinary consumption into an engine of broad-based asset ownership.
Next step: Phase-1 pilot launches this quarter. Join the wait-list and watch ABI appear in a real wallet to see post-labor economics in action.
[1] Blue line (left axis) – Wage share of national income: down from ~64% in 2000 to ~56% in 2024 (-8 ppts). Green line (right axis) – Real GDP index (2000 = 100): up about 50% over the same period.
Last updated